(Reprinted from HKCER Letters, Vol. 42, January, 1997)
How Severe is the Housing Shortage in Hong Kong?
Y.C. Richard Wong
Introduction
Rising property prices in Hong Kong have been of great public concern throughout most of the 1990s. Speculators have been blamed for setting off periodic episodes of property price hikes. Public policy has until now been focused primarily on curbing speculative activities. This is most unfortunate, because curbing speculation will not hold down property prices in the face of sustained increases in housing demand. Luckily, the recently released consultative document on long-term housing review, entitled Homes for Hong Kong People: the Way Forward, has been able to address a broader range of housing issues.
My purpose here is to focus attention on the nature of the housing shortage in Hong Kong so as to understand the sustained escalation of property prices that has been taking place for almost a decade. Figure 1 shows that with the exception of the periods 1989-1990 and 1994-1995, real property prices have been rising steadily at an annual rate of 2.14 percent over the past 15 years. This is due to a slow increase in the available housing stock coupled with rapid growth in the demand for housing.
The factors that have contributed to demand growth are by now well known. They include rising incomes due to a sustained economic boom, which is in turn due in part to the successful opening of China; a population that is growing as a result of immigration; a shift in the population's age structure towards one in which age groups with a high demand for housing is growing; low nominal interest rates because of the linked exchange rate regime that ties the domestic interest rate to the U.S. rate; and a high rate of domestic inflation because of supply side constraints in a booming economy.
This sustained growth in housing demand has not only increased the demand for housing units, it has, more importantly, encouraged "trading up" activity. Better-quality housing has in general been in greater demand in recent years, quality being defined here in terms of larger units, better location, enhanced aesthetic and construction quality, and improved facilities and amenities. This change is borne out by the fact that property prices of better-quality housing units have risen far more than have those of other units, and the frequency at which these units are being bought and sold is also proportionately much higher.
On the supply side, the total stock of housing units in Hong Kong has grown over time, but its growth rate fluctuates considerably in response to market conditions, and has tended to decline over time (see Table 1). The relative decline in the 1990s is anomalous given the very robust market conditions. This decline suggests that the shortage of land, the difficulties of redevelopment, and regulatory restrictions may be slowing the supply response.
On the demand side, although the number of households in Hong Kong is increasing, it is doing so at a lower rate. As a consequence, the number of households and the number of housing units have come close to achieving a balance throughout the 1990s. While this seems to suggest that every household can, by itself, now occupy a residential unit, it should not be taken to indicate that there is a balance in the supply of and demand for housing. If this were in fact the case, housing prices would not have continued to rise in the past decade.
Stock of HousingThe total number of units available is a poor measure of the total supply of housing in the market because it fails to take into account floor area, location, year of completion, and other quality attributes of housing. In order to accurately measure the total supply of housing in Hong Kong, one must first differentiate between public and private housing units. Public housing units can be further broadly classified into rental units and owner-occupied units.
The average sizes of rental units and owner-occupied units in the public sector differ greatly. Table 2 shows that between 1982 and 1996 the average size of rental units increased from 24.58 to 30.85 square meters, and for owner-occupied units it increased from 52.24 to 55.10 square meters. It is apparent that lumping together rental and owner-occupied units would not be an appropriate way to measure the total supply of public housing. Some method of standardizing different types of units is obviously necessary in order to obtain an accurate idea of how much housing is actually available.
There is also a great deal of difference between the average size of private residential units and that of public housing units. The average size of available private residential units has been remarkably stable over time, remaining at about 55 square meters (see Table 2). Although the average size of the private units completed each year has been rising, this increase has had little impact on the average size of the available housing units, overall.
To facilitate comparison between different types of public housing units on the one hand and private housing units on the other, it is useful to treat a private housing unit as a standard housing unit (with a mean size of approximately 55 square meters). A public owner-occupied unit is about the same size as a private housing unit and will therefore be treated as equal to a standard housing unit. A public rental unit is about 60 percent of the size of an average private housing unit and will be set equal to 0.6 times a standard housing unit.
Table 1 sets forth the total stock of public and private housing units in terms of actual numbers and standardized units. While the number of actual units is larger than is the number of standardized units, standardized units are actually growing at a faster rate, because of the shift in composition towards larger units. What is more important, however, is that the gap between households and the housing stock ceases to be balanced once we begin to base our concept of the housing stock on standard units rather than on actual units.
Indeed, according to my calculations, we have a hypothetical shortage of 273,000 standard units at the present time. This shortage manifests itself primarily in the fact that a large number of public housing units are too small to meet the housing aspirations of the tenants who occupy them, they are willing to stay there only because of the very cheap subsidized rent. It is important to take note of two relevant points. The firstpoint is that the units are standardized only in terms of size. Most public housing units are on average of relatively low quality. Furthermore, almost all public housing units are governed by tenancy agreements and terms of ownership that impose severe limits on tenant mobility and asset transferability, so that public and private units are far from being perfect substitutes. The second point is that the distribution of income among tenants in the public and private housing sectors are not terribly different. Therefore, the differential demand for housing among tenants in one of these two sectors versus the other will not be sufficient to alter our conclusion about the severity of the housing shortage.
Households and Housing StockIt is instructive to examine the historical record of the match between the number of households and the housing stock. Since the last market crash in 1981, the gap between the number of households in Hong Kong and the number of actual housing units, both private and public, decreased steadily until 1994; however the gap widened in 1995 as a result of the increased number of immigrants returning to the city. Yet the real price of housing has been on an upward trend since 1984. This indicates that the gap between the number of households and the number of actual housing units in the stock is not a good indicator of whether or not there is a housing shortage. In particular, it is not a good predictor of price movements. Even if there were more housing units than households, prices would not necessarily stabilize. The reasons for this are as follows:
1. Existing house-holds will split into more households as young people marry and live apart from their parents.
2. In a housing market, under normal circumstances, there should be a certain percent of vacancy in the housing stock to accommodate changes in tenancy, renovation, etc.
3. Households may occupy more than one housing unit. Some high-income households may own a second unit as a vacation home.
4. Households living in public housing may also occupy more than one housing unit for a different reason. The Housing Authority estimated that about 13 percent of public rental housing tenants, or about 74,000 households, own private domestic properties. The flats they own account for as many as 11 percent of all private housing units. Among the private housing units owned by public housing tenants, 84 percent are owner occupied, with the remaining 16 percent being rented out. Therefore, what happens in most cases is that some registered members of the households who are supposedly living in public rental housing are in fact residing in private flats they own. They could be the sons, daughters, or parents of the heads of these households. In extreme cases, all members of the household will reside in their own private flats, leaving the public rental units vacant. This trend of private home ownership by public rental housing tenants appears to be on the rise. A random sampling of 2000 transactions in the period between October 1992 and March 1993 provided by the Rating and Evaluating Department shows that as many as 24 percent of private housing units were purchased by public rental housing tenants. This phenomenon suggests that there is considerable absenteeism in public rental housing. A survey taken by the Housing Department in August 1992 showed that as many as 18 percent of public rental tenant households had some registered members not currently living in the flat. Therefore the de facto household size is likely to be considerably smaller than is the authorized household size. Alternatively, it means that the actual number of households in Hong Kong could be considerably larger than the number reported in the statistics. Hence, when the statistics show a surplus of housing units over the number of households, there could in actual fact be a shortage.
5. Finally, even if the properly measured number of households matches the number of housing units, there will still be pressure for prices to increase, because real income growth will allow households to trade up-market by selling the existing units they occupy and buying larger and higher-quality units. This will push prices up at the middle to the upper end of the market, while prices at the lower end of the market will stagnate or even fall. However, the private housing market will adjust, for units that are not in large demand will be demolished and redeveloped into larger units that are in higher demand. The average unit size and the quality of the housing stock will increase over time, and housing prices will grow higher.
The above discussion suggests that the standardized housing stock, in which public housing units are converted into equivalent private housing units on the basis of area, is a better measure of available housing than is the actual housing stock. Between 1982 and 1996 there has been a substantial shortage of housing measured in standardized units when we compare the number of households with the standardized housing stock.
Y.C. Richard Wong is Director of the Hong Kong Centre for Economic Research and the professor of School of Economics and Finance in the University of Hong Kong.
Table 1: Number of Households and Housing Stock: 1978-1996 (thousands)
Number Housing Stock
Households minus of Private Public Housing
Total
Housing Stock.
Year Households Housing Renter Owner Actual Standard Actual Standard Occupied
1982 1319 522 505 26 1053 851 266 468 1983 1350 542 533 36 1111 897 239 453 1984 1405 563 554 48 1165 943 240 462 1985 1435 592 572 67 1231 1002 204 432 1986 1488 625 579 81 1285 1053 203 435 1987 1515 658 596 86 1340 1101 175 413 1988 1544 692 621 98 1411 1162 133 381 1989 1553 726 651 118 1495 1234 59 319 1990 1574 753 667 130 1550 1283 24 291 1991 1622 781 681 143 1605 1333 17 289 1992 1663 805 672 166 1643 1374 20 289 1993 1706 833 677 186 1696 1425 10 281 1994 1763 866 684 204 1754 1480 9 283 1995 1815 886 691 222 1799 1523 16 292 1996 1840 903 708 239 1850 1567 -10 273
Note: Figures for 1996 are estimated.
Table 2: Residential Housing: Average Size (m2)
Private Public Annual Owner Year Stock Supply Rental Occupied
1982 56.68 24.58 52.24 1983 55.65 60.64 24.93 53.82 1984 55.19 43.37 24.48 52.21 1985 54.58 43.68 24.53 51.77 1986 54.32 50.42 27.52 51.45 1987 54.23 53.85 25.38 51.93 1988 54.44 58.36 25.81 51.96 1989 54.73 61.09 27.73 52.16 1990 54.78 57.41 28.27 52.39 1991 54.85 59.90 28.22 52.84 1992 54.79 53.75 28.53 53.21 1993 54.73 54.18 29.20 53.72 1994 54.57 56.11 29.86 54.11 1995 55.74 63.20 30.03 54.80 1996 55.94 65.40 30.85 55.10
Figure:1
|
Index | Research Projects |
HKCER Letters | | Speaker Program / Conference | Index of Economic Freedom | |
||
The Hong Kong Centre
for Economic Research School of Economics and Finance The University of Hong Kong Phone: (852) 2547-8313 Fax: (852) 2548-6319 email: hkcer@econ.hku.hk |